History, Big History, & Metahistory
DOI: 10.37911/9781947864023.08
8. Labeling & Analyzing Historical Phenomena: Some Preliminary Challenges
Author: Kenneth Pomeranz, University of Chicago
Excerpt
A serious obstacle to the search for a more scientific history is that humans label themselves and their actions. These labels can be extremely sticky and often obscure the categories which might be most useful for seeking regularities. Another, related, problem is a focus on dramatic events that seem to be relatively rare and are commonly recognized as landmarks, e.g. political and industrial revolutions. Having formed several of these major events into a class, scientifically-minded historians have then often searched for a very small set of discrete variables that could predict the occurrence or non-occurrence of these very special events. By contrast, I would argue that we are likely to be better off by looking at more general processes that may include but are not limited to these dramatic events, and looking for clusters of variables which interact with each other; the hoped-for result would usually be not to explain the categorical presence or absence of some process (e.g., “economic development”) but to group many cases into families, seeking to explain both within-group and between-group variation by means of systematic comparison.
Naming Historical Events and Processes: Problems of Familiarity
Historians often say that because they study processes in which the participants are consciously trying to affect the results, they cannot be expected to come up with generalizations comparable to those found by people studying, say, microbes or electrons. But human volition need not be a fatal obstacle to the search for a more scientific history; it does not rule out the possibility that there are regularities to be found in these human responses, at various levels of aggregation.
A bigger problem, I would argue, is that humans label themselves and their actions; these labels can be extremely sticky and often obscure the categories which might be most useful for seeking regularities. Moreover, people interested in a more scientific history cohabit with both professionals and amateurs whose efforts (often in reaction to the emic labels of participants) strongly skew the set of topics in which we are interested and the units we choose for looking at them away from those which might be most promising for developing generalizations.
References
[1] Hunt, Lynn. “Introduction: History, Culture and Text.” In Lynn Hunt, ed., The New Cultural History. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1989.
[2] Beasley, W.G., and E.G. Pulleyblank, eds. Historians of China and Japan. London: Oxford University Press, 1961.
[3] Bray, Francesca. The Rice Economies. Oxford, New York: Blackwell, 1986
[4] Sugihara, Kaoru. “The East Asian Path of Economic Development: A Long-term Perspective,” in Giovanni Arrighi, Takeshi Hamashita, and Mark Selden, eds., The Resurgence of East Asia: 500, 150 and 50 Year Perspectives (London: Routledge, 2003), pp.78-123.
[5] Pomeranz, Kenneth. “Chinese Development in Long-run Perspective,” Proceedings of the American Philosophical Society 152:1 (March, 2008), pp. 83-100.
[6] Scott, James C. The Art of Not Being Governed: An Anarchist History of Upland Southeast Asia. New Haven: Yale University Press, 2009.
[7] Duara, Prasenjit. Rescuing History From the Nation: Questioning Narratives of Modern China. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1995.
[8] Tanaka, Stefan. Japan’s Orient: Rendering Pasts into History. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1993.
[9] Brinton, Crane. The Anatomy of Revolution. New York: Vintage, 1952.
[10] Moore, Barrington. Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy: Lord and Peasant in the Making of the Modern World. Boston: Beacon Press, 1967.
[11] Skocpol, Theda. States and Social Revolutions: A Comparative Analysis of France, Russia, and China. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1979.
[12] Goldstone, Jack. Revolution and Rebellion in the Early Modern World. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1991.
[13] Sahlins, Marshall. Culture and Practical Reason. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1976.
[14] Tilly, Charles. “Town and Country in Revolution.” Working Paper #84, Center for Research on Social Organization, 1973.
[15] Guha, Ranajit. Elementary Aspects of Peasant Insurgency in India. Durhan, NC: Duke University Press, 1999.
[16] Marx, Karl. The Eighteenth Brumaire of Louis Napoleon. New York: International Publishers, 1963. (Original edition, 1852).
[17] Merriman, John. The Agony of the Republic: The Repression of the Left in Revolutionary France, 1848—1851. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1978.
[18] Agulhon, Maurice. La République au village: Les populations du Var de la Révolution au IIe République. 2nd Edition. Paris: Seuil, 1979.
[19] Margadant, Ted. French Peasants in Revolt: The Insurrection of 1851. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1979.
[20] Tilly, Charles. “To Explain Political Processes,” American Journal of Sociology 100:6 (May, 1995), pp. 1594-1610.
[21] Pomeranz, Kenneth. “Chinese Development in Long-run Perspective,” Proceedings of the American Philosophical Society 152:1 (March, 2008), pp. 83-100.
[22] Rostow, W.W. The Stages of Growth: A Non-Communist Manifesto. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press, 1960.
[23] Jones, Eric. “Patterns of Growth in History.” In Capitalism in Context: Essays on Economic Development and Cultural Change in Honor of R. M. Hartwell, ed. John A. James and Mark Thomas. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1994, 15 (attributing this view to R. M. Hartwell).
[24] Crafts, N.F.R. British Economic Growth During the Industrial Revolution. Oxford: Clarendon, 1985.
[25] Goldstone, Jack. “Efflorescences and Economic Growth in World History: Rethinking the ‘Rise of the West’ and the Industrial Revolution,” Journal of World History 13:2 (2002), pp. 323-389. 2002
[26] Pomeranz, Kenneth. “Le machinisme induit-il une discontinuité historique ? Industrialisation, modernité précoce et formes du changement économique dans l’histoire globale,” in Beaujard P., Berger L. and Norel P. (eds), Histoire globale, mondialisations, capitalisme (Paris: La découverte, 2009), 335 -373.
[27] North, Douglass, and Barry Weingast, “Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth Century England,” Journal of Economic History 49:4 (December, 1989), pp. 803-832.
[28] Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson. 2002. “Reversal of Fortune: Geography and Institutions in the Making of the Modern World Income Distribution,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117:4 (November): 1231-1294.
[29] Allen, Robert. “Agricultural Productivity and Rural Incomes in England and the Yangtze Delta, ca. 1620-1820,” Economic History Review 62:3 (August, 2009), pp. 525-550.
[30] Allen, Robert, Jean-Pascal Bassino, Debin Ma, Christine Moll-Murata, and Jan LuitenVan Zanden, “Wages, Prices and Living Standards in China, Japan, and Europe, 1738-1925.” http://www.nuff.ox.ac.uk/Users/Allen/unpublished/allen%20et %20all%202007i(7-dp).pdf.
[31] Pomeranz, Kenneth. “Standards of Living in Rural and Urban China: Preliminary Estimates for the Mid 18th and Early twentieth Centuries.” Paper for Panel 77 of International Economic History Association Conference, Helsinki, 2006.
[32] DeVries, Jan. European Urbanization, 1500—1800 (London: Metheun 1984), 39.
[33] Skinner, G. William, “Regional Urbanization in Nineteeenth Century China,” in G. William Skinner, ed., The City in Late Imperial China (Stanford University Press, 1977), 229 .
[34] Skinner, G. William, “Sichuan’s Population in the 19th Century: Lessons From Disaggregated Data,” Late Imperial China 8:1 (June, 1987) pp. 1-79.
[35] Xue Yong, “Agrarian Urbanization: Social and Economic Changes in Jiangnan from the Eight to the Nineteenth Century” (Yale University Ph. D. dissertation, 2006), pp. 432-470.
[36] Li Bozhong. Agricultural Development in Jiangnan, 1620-1850. New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1998.
[37] Van Zanden, Jan Luiten, “Estimating Early Modern Economic Growth” (Working Paper, International Institute of Social History, University of Utrecht, 2004. Available at http://www.iisg.nl/research/jvz-estimating.pdf, accessed December 17, 2007), pp. 22-23.
[38] Ma, Debin. “Modern Economic Growth in the Lower Yangzi in 1911-1937: A Quantitative, Historical, and Institutional Analysis.” Discussion paper 2004-06-002, p. 6. Foundation for Advanced Studies on International Development, Tokyo, 2004.
[39] Lee, James, and Wang Feng. One Quarter of Humanity: Malthusian Mythologies and Chinese Realities. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1999.
[40] Lee, James, and Cameron Campbell. Fate and Fortune in Rural China: Social Organization and Population Behavior in Liaoning, 1774-1873. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997.
[41] Liu Ts’ui-jung. “Demographic Constraint and Family Stucture in Traditional Chinese Lineages.” In Stevan Harrell, ed.,Chinese Historical Microdemography (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1995), pp. 121-140.
[42] Zhang Peiguo. Jindai Jiangnan xiangcun diquan de lishi renleixue yanjiu. (Historical Anthropology of Land Rights in Modern Jiangnan Villages.) Shanghai: shanghai renmin chubanshe, 2002.
[43] Buck, John.L. Land Utilization in China. Shanghai: Commercial Press,1937; reprint edition, New York,: Paragon, 1964.
[44] Jing Su and Luo Lun. Qing dai Shandong jingying dizhu jingnji yanjiu (revised edition of 1958 text). (Economic Research on Managerial Landlords in Qing Dynasty Shandong.) Jinan: Qilu shushe, 1986.
[45] Li Wenzhi and Jiang Taixin. Zhongguo dizhu zhidu jingji lun. (An Economic Discourse on China’s Landlord System.) Beijing: Shehui kexue chubanshe, 2005
[46] Yang, C.K. “Some Preliminary Statistical Patterns of Mass Actions in Nineteenth-Century China.” In Conflict and Control in Late Imperial China, eds. Frederic Wakeman and Carolyn Grant, pp. 186-187. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 1975.
[47] Pomeranz, Kenneth. The Great Divergence: China, Europe, and the Making of the Modern World Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2000.
[48] West, Geoffrey. “Can there be a Quantitative Theory for the History of Life and Society?” Cliodynamics 2:1 (2011).
[49] Osamu, Saito. Puroto-Kōgyōka no jidai: Seiō to Nihon no hikakushi. (The Age of Proto-Industrialization: A Comparative History of Western Europe and Japan.) Tokyo: Nihon Hyronsha, 1985.
[50] Cerman, Markus, and Sheilagh Ogilvie, eds. European Proto-Industrialization. Cambridge; Cambridge University Press, 1996.
[51] Epstein, S.R., and Maarten Prak, eds., Guilds, Innovation, and the European Economy, 1400-1800. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press, 2008.
[52] Rosenthal, Jean Laurent, and R. Bin Wong. Before and Beyond Divergence. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, forthcoming, 2011.
[53] Li Bozhong. Jiangnan de zaoqi gongyehua. (The Early Industrialization of The Yangzi Delta Region.) Beijing: shehui kexue wenxian chubanshe, 2000.
[54] Terje Tvedt, “Why England and not China and India? Water Systems and the History of the Industrial Revolution,” Journal of Global History 5:1 (March, 2010), pp. 29-50.
[55] Van Slyke, Lyman. Yangtze: Nature, History, and the River. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley, 1988, p. 15.
[56] Allen, Robert C. “Mr. Lockyer Meets the Index Number Problem: The Standard of Living in Canton and London in 1704,. Available at http://www. iisg.nl/hpw/papers/allen.pdf, accessed December 7, 2008.
[57] Pomeranz, Kenneth. The Making of a Hinterland: State, Society, and Economy, in Inland North China, 1853—1937. Berkeley: University of California Press 1993.
[58] Dodgen, Randall. Controlling the Dragon: Confucian Engineers and the Yellow River in Late Imperial China. Honolulu: University of Hawaii Press, 2001.
[59] Morgan, Stephen. “Economic Growth and the Biological Standard of Living in China 1880-1930,” Economic and Human Biology 2:2 (2004), pp. 197-218.
[60] Rawski, Thomas G. Economic Growth in Prewar China. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1989.
[61] Ma Junya. Hunhe yu fazhan: Jiangnan diqu chuantong shehui jingji de xiandai yanbian (1900-1950). (Mixture and Development: The Modern Evolution of Traditional Society and Economy in the Jiangnan District, 1900-1950.) Beijing: Shehui kexue wenxian chubanshe, 2002.
[62] Xia Mingfang. Minguo shiqi ziran hai yu xiangcun shehui. (Natural Disasters and Village Society in the Republican Era) Beijing: Zhonghua shuju, 2000.
[63] Diamond, Jared. Guns, Germs and Steel: The Fates of Human Societies. New York: W.W. Norton, 1997.
[64] Gell-Mann, Murray. “Regularities in Human Affairs.” Cliodynamics 2:1 (2011).
[65] Brush, Stephen G. “Are the Soft Sciences Too Hard?” Contentions 4:2 (1995): 3-12.
[66] Wong, R.B. China Transformed: Historical Change and the Limits of European Experience. Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1997
[67] Austin, Gareth. 2007. “Reciprocal Comparison and African History: Tackling Conceptual Eurocentrism in the Study of Africa’s Economic Past,” African Studies Review 50:3 (December), 1-28.
[68] Levine, David. Family Formation in an Age of Nascent Capitalism. New York: Academic Press, 1977.
[69] Kriedte, Peter, Medick, Hans., and Schlumbohm,Jürgen. Industrialization Before Industrialization. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1981.
[70] Mendels, Frankin F. “Proto-industrialization: the First Phase of Industrialization,” 32:1 (1972), pp. 241-261
[71] Stockard, Janice. Daughters of the Canton Delta: Marriage Patterns and Economic Strategies in South China, 1860-1930. Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1989.
[72] Friedman, Milton. “The Methodology of Positive Economics.” In Friedman, Essays in Positive Economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1953.
[73] Berg, Nathan and Gerd Gigerenzer. “As-If Behavioral Economics: Neoclassical Economics in Disguise?” History of Economic Ideas 18 (2010), 133-165.
[74] McCloskey, Donald. “English Open Fields as Behavior Toward Risk,” in P. Uselding, ed., Research in Economic History Vol. 1 (Greenwich, CT: JAI Press, 1976), pp. 124-170.
[75] Eley, Geoff. The Crooked Line: From Cultural History to the History of Society. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press, 2005.